How We Hire Writers

custom writing

All applicants go through a series of tests that check their level of English and knowledge of formatting styles. The applicant is also required to present a sample of writing to the Evaluation Department. If you wish to find out more about the procedure, check out the whole process.

How We Ensure Quality

Our Quality Control Department checks every single order for formatting, style, word usage, and authenticity. This lets us deliver certified assignment assistance that has no Internet rivals.

Case1.pdf

Harvard Business School 9-297-090February 16, 1997

Lecturer Alberto Moel and Professor Robert C. Merton prepared this note as the basis for class discussion rather than toillustrate either effective or ineffective handling of an administrative situation.

Copyright © 1997 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. To order copies or request permission toreproduce materials, call 1-800-545-7685 or write Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA 02163. Nopart of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted inany form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without thepermission of Harvard Business School.

1

Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets

This note provides a brief overview of the history of the Savings and Loans, the Savings andLoans crisis of the 1980s and early 1990s, and the creation of the mortgage markets in the U.S. It alsoexplains briefly the most common types of mortgage-backed securities (MBS) available.

Savings and Loans Before the Crisis

Savings & Loans (S&Ls) first appeared as financial intermediaries in the early to mid-1800s.The principal role of the S&Ls was to take in retail deposits (providing a riskless, liquid, short-termsavings vehicle for large numbers of small savers) and originate long-term fixed-rate mortgagefinancing for residential homeowners. S&Ls were originally voluntary associations. People pooledtheir money to make it possible for members of the association to get mortgages on their homeswithout having to resort to loan sharks or to other forms of usury. The first documented mortgagetransaction occurred in 1831, when Isaac Shallcross, as secretary of the first S&L made a $381mortgage loan to lamp-lighter Comly Rich. Rich bought a house that still stands in the Frankfordsuburb of Philadelphia.

S&Ls were (and still are) community-based, and local in nature. This is partly due totradition and to prohibitions against out-of-state lending, but it is also because mortgage originationis mostly a local business. People with knowledge of local real-estate market conditions need toparticipate in the mortgage application and appraisal process, as well as deal with the loan andproperty in case of default. Thus, even though the source of funds might be distant, agents of thelender need to be locally based, so they will have access to the necessary data to make an informeddecision. There is evidence that information and incentive problems increase as the distance betweenthe lender and the borrower grows. One 1948 study of savings banks, for example, found a directcorrelation between loan loss rates and the distance of the loan from the home office.

Another important aspect of the thrifts before the S&L crisis was their capital structure. Thevoluntary nature of the early thrifts gave rise to an unusual corporate form. The vast majority ofthrifts were not established as stock corporations, but as mutual associations. In a mutual association,the thrift is organized as a cooperative owned by its members. Member’s deposits represent shares,and shareholders vote on company matters and receive interest on their deposits in the form ofdividends. Mutual associations are not permitted to issue stock, and deposits (i.e. “shares”) aretechnically subject to a waiting period before withdrawal. In practice, withdrawals are usually ondemand, with the thrift’s liquidity assured by its ability to borrow from the Federal Home Loan

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

297-090 Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets

2

Banks (described below) using home mortgages as collateral. Prior to the S&L crisis, regulationsconstrained most thrifts to be mutually owned.

The Rise of the Mortgage Markets

Attempts in the 1800s to overcome the community-based lending structure of S&Ls failed. Itwasn’t until the Great Depression in the 1930s, that permanent change was forthcoming. Seeking therevival of the housing industry, Herbert Hoover’s administration formed the Federal Home LoanBank System (FHLB), a dozen district public-purpose “banks”, owned (like the Federal ReserveBanks) by their member institutions. The FHLB banks were controlled by a national Board (theFHLBB) appointed by the President and confirmed by the Senate. The Housing Act of 1934 added aHome Owners Loan Corporation (later renamed the Federal National Mortgage Association, orFannie Mae), which bought mortgages from S&Ls. The Act also empowered the FHLBB to issuenational charters for S&Ls (which despite their national charter were restricted to their state oforigin)1 and established the Federal Housing Administration (FHA).

It was through the FHA that the first steps in the formation of national mortgage marketswere taken. The FHA offered credit insurance on mortgages that met the underwriting standards itestablished. It also developed the long-term self-amortizing mortgage that became the standardstructure in residential financing. The FHA not only provided means for reducing credit risk tolenders, but also set the stage for the standardization of the lending criteria and mortgage terms, bothof which were fundamental in the later development of the securitization process.

While these were important advances, they did not expand the mortgage markets from alocal to an inter-regional or long-distance market. Until the mid-60s, the S&L business was secure,profitable, and dull. S&L managers operated under the well known 3-6-3 rule: borrow fromdepositors at 3%, lend to home buyers at 6%, and arrive at the golf course by 3:00 PM. In 1970,savings institutions accounted for 60% of the outstanding home mortgages. The large majority ofthese institutions made mortgage loans only within their home state, and often within a morenarrowly defined home region or lending area. The volume of mortgage loans available within aparticular region was limited by the funds available to the local depository institutions.

By the late 1960s, when interest rates began to rise and became more volatile, there were 4,508S&Ls, with total assets of $124.6 billion. This rise and increased volatility of interest rates causeddifficulties for the S&Ls, which make their profit from interest rate spreads — the difference betweenwhat they collected in mortgage-loan interest and what they paid to depositors. If interest rates drop,borrowers have the option of refinancing, so the thrift gets its money back sooner than it wants andhas to reinvest at a lower rate. Of course, the thrift also pays lower interest rates on the deposits,offsetting some of this interest rate risk. However, as interest rates rose, borrowers held on to their(fixed-rate) mortgages, and the thrifts were stuck paying more for deposits than they earned on theirloans.

Compounding the problem, interest rate ceilings, such as the Federal Reserve’s Regulation Q,prevented S&Ls from paying competitive interest rates on deposits. Thus, every time interest ratesrose, substantial amounts of funds were withdrawn by consumers for placement in instruments withhigher rates of return, such as mutual funds. This process of deposit withdrawal(“disintermediation”) and the subsequent deposit influx when rates rose (“reintermediation”) leftS&Ls highly vulnerable. S&Ls were additionally restricted by not being allowed to enter intobusinesses other than accepting deposits and granting home mortgage loans.

1 Even more importantly, they were only permitted to lend within a fifty-mile radius of a branch office.

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets 297-090

3

In response to the resulting increase in lending institutions’ cost of funds and the growingdisintermediation problem, the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae) and the FederalHome Loan Mortgage Association (Freddie Mac, formed in early 1970 by the FHLBB) wereauthorized in 1970 to purchase pools of mortgages and to issue securities collateralized by the pools.Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, as federally-sponsored entities, guaranteed the payment of interest andprincipal. The Government National Mortgage Association (Ginnie Mae, created by the Johnsonadministration in the 1960s) also supported securitization by insuring private securitization of FHA-guaranteed mortgages. These securitized pools of mortgages are known as Mortgage Backed Securities(MBS) pass-throughs. This way, thrifts could package and sell their mortgage loans, removing themfrom the balance sheet and injecting liquidity to the institution.

Until 1977, all pass-through securities carried the full backing of the US government. In 1977,the first private mortgage pass-through not guaranteed by the government was issued by Bank ofAmerica. Nowadays, commercial banks, investment banks, and others package privately-issuedmortgages and issue securities backed by pools of mortgages. There are a number of creditenhancement techniques: the issuer of the securities can guarantee the MBS if it has a high enoughcredit rating, or credit insurance can be purchased from a specialized insurer.

The issuance of these mortgage securities made investing in the mortgage market moreappealing to an even greater institutional investor base, which had found the investment inindividual mortgages a risky proposition. As issuers of these simple MBS pass-throughs becamemore comfortable with the securitization process, other types of mortgages, such as adjustable ratemortgages, were also securitized.

Mortgage securitization has transformed a highly localized lending market into one in whichcountry-wide and even international lending is common. Of the $1 trillion of mortgages outstandingin the United States in 1993, 63% of them were securitized. By 1996, the amount outstanding was $3.8trillion (which corresponded to 32% of all public and private debt outstanding), of which over $3trillion was securitized.

Mortgage securitization has made the transfer of resources much more efficient byeliminating the link between the origination (which is still a local business) and the funding of theloan. Additionally, securitization has also facilitated easier matching of cash flow requirements overtime. The typical long-term fixed rate mortgage loan offers is advantageous to the borrower.However, this single instrument might not be the optimal investment vehicle for investors, or even forthe savings institutions that originated the mortgages in the first place. By splitting the securitizedmortgage pools into instruments of different maturities,2 it has been possible to design differentmortgage instruments that appeal to different investors.

For example, pension funds have a need for very long-duration assets to match their verylong liabilities. With MBS, it is possible to create very long-duration assets by separating the longest-dated cash flows from the mortgage pool. In a similar fashion, instruments were created to meet theneeds of commercial banks, pension funds, and other financial intermediaries. As a measure of therelevance of MBS to other financial intermediaries, in 1993, only 11% of MBS were owned by savingsand loans, while 26% were owned by banks, and 13% by pension funds.

2 Some of these instruments are described below.

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

297-090 Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets

4

The Savings and Loans Crisis

Also in response to the problem of disintermediation in the late 60s, state and federalgovernments began the deregulation of the industry and the application of measures to ensure theviability of the S&Ls.

For example, after a number of California thrifts failed in 1966 after the Fed raised interestrates to control Vietnam war-induced inflation, the FHLB, in response, allowed S&Ls to pay a 0.25%differential on insured deposits over the maximum rates permitted to the banks under Regulation Q.Another important step was the gradual lifting of restrictions (beginning in 1970 in California) on theissuance of adjustable-rate (ARM) mortgages.

Regulatory “forbearance” was also begun in this period with respect to loosening restrictionson S&L assets. For example, the State of Texas allowed property development loans of up to 50% of abank’s equity in 1967, and in 1978, the Financial Institutions Regulatory and Interest Rate Control Actallowed S&Ls to invest up to 5% of assets in each of land development, construction, and educationloans.

In 1979, the problems facing the S&L industry intensified. Oil prices doubled, inflationmoved into double digits for the second time in five years, and the Federal Reserve decided to targetthe money supply in order to control inflation, letting interest rates not only rise, but become evenmore volatile. As the prime rate hit 21%, certificates of deposit issued by the S&Ls went for as high as15%, while their income came in the form of long-term lending of fixed rate mortgages, many made at7% or 8%. Additionally, Regulation Q led to a large drain of deposits out of thrifts and intounregulated investment vehicles (such as Eurodollar deposits and mutual funds), furtherexacerbating their problems.

In response, the government enacted statutory and regulatory changes that gave the S&Lindustry new powers so they could enter new areas of business and return to profitability. For thefirst time, the government approved measures intended to increase S&L profits as opposed topromoting home-ownership. In March 1980, the Depository Institutions Deregulation and MonetaryControl Act (DIDMCA) was enacted.

DIDMCA was an initiative aimed at eliminating many of the distinctions among differenttypes of depository institutions and ultimately removing interest rate ceilings on deposit accounts.DIDMCA authorized all depository institutions to offer interest-bearing checkable deposits, such asNOW accounts, and mandated the elimination of Regulation Q by 1986. DIDMCA also allowed theFederal Savings and Loans Insurance Corporation (FSLIC), the government-sponsored S&L depositinsurance corporation, to raise insurance deposit limits from $40,000 per account to $100,000. Thisincreased the protection of the thrifts by the government, but had the added perverse effect ofallowing thrift managers to “gamble” with insured deposits.3 Finally, DIDMCA allowed insuredthrifts to invest in broader, riskier classes of assets, such as real estate and ADC (acquisition,development, and construction) loans. Removing these asset restrictions was viewed by some as astep towards deregulation, which would allow thrifts to diversify and grow their way back to health,but was seen by others as a reduction in the intensity of monitoring of insured thrifts, which wouldcause further problems down the road.

3 This is an example of the well-known “moral-hazard” problem. In this case, the government socialized anddistributed the risk of questionable loans, while leaving the potential rewards private. Another illustrativeexample is the increased incidence of speeding or reckless driving as cars with enhanced safety measures suchas anti-lock brakes or airbags become more common.

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets 297-090

5

This regulatory forbearance, begun with DIDMCA, and aimed at having S&Ls growthemselves into profitability, continued through the early 1980s. The regulations and statutes enactedwere many and varied, but five of them stand out as being particularly relevant.

1. In November 1980, the Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB) reduced the networth requirement for FSLIC-insured S&Ls from 5 to 4% of total deposits, andremoved the limits on the amount of brokered deposits4 an S&L could hold. InJanuary, 1982, the FHLBB further reduced the net worth requirement from 4 to3% of total deposits. Additionally, S&Ls were allowed to meet the low net worthstandard not in terms of generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP) but ofthe more liberal regulatory accounting principles (RAP). This relaxation inaccounting standards and net worth requirement allowed some of the insolventthrifts to become statutorily (but not economically) solvent.

2. The approval of “Memorandum R-49”, by the FHLBB in September, 1981. Thememorandum encouraged “loss deferral.” Loss deferral allowed S&Ls to sellloans on which they showed a loss and amortize the loss over the life of the loan.An additional “safe harbor” clause was inserted to allow the S&Ls to show thetotal amount of the loss only for tax purposes when the assets were sold (therebygenerating a tax credit for the year.) By encouraging S&Ls to dispose of badloans and mortgages, funds could be released for ostensibly safer and moreprofitable investments. However, the new loans issued were not necessarilysafer. Under the new rules, S&Ls could buy even riskier investments, such asbelow-investment grade bonds (“junk bonds.”)

3. The Garn-St. Germain Depository Institutions Act of 1982 further expanded theclasses of assets that a thrift could invest in, and changed the procedures forrescuing insolvent S&Ls through merger. The Act changed the FHLBBaccounting rules to permit an S&L that acquired another to capitalize asgoodwill the difference between the net worth of the acquired institution and theprice paid for it, and to allow the amortization of goodwill to occur over fortyyears. The result was that insolvent, money-losing S&Ls would be worth moreto an acquirer than sound ones, because the goodwill that could be booked insuch a transaction would permit a larger increase in the acquirer’s statutorycapital, allowing greater opportunities of expansion of the loan portfolio.

4. The Garn-St. Germain Act also included a provision that legalized andencouraged mutual associations to convert voluntarily to stock ownership. Theproponents of stock conversion believed that the Act represented a chance tobolster the thrift’s capital positions (through equity issuance) and would lead tohigher efficiency through better monitoring of managers by stockholders. Beforethe passage of the Act, 77% of thrifts were mutual associations, and 23% werestock owned. Stock owned institutions controlled about 30% of the industry’sassets. Between 1982 and 1986, close to 500 thrifts converted to stock ownership,raising over $5.3 billion in equity capital. Also, 75% of new institutions opted forstock ownership. By 1988, over 70% of the industry’s assets were held in stockowned institutions. Consistent with the theory of equity holder’s incentives,5

4 Brokered deposits are funds packaged by brokerage houses in units of $100,000, to be eligible for depositinsurance. They are then placed in thrifts and commercial banks as deposits, earning market rates of interest,and serving as funding sources for the institutions.5 In a stock-owned thrift, the shareholders are residual claimants, and their claims can be transferred via a saleof stock. Specifically, shareholders hold the equivalent of a call option on risky assets. As a result, they haveincentives to increase the riskiness of the underlying assets and to take on additional debt. The shareholders

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

297-090 Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets

6

stock-owned thrifts grew faster, had higher leverage, went out of the localmarket to obtain brokered deposits, and sold more of their mortgages forsecuritization than did mutuals. Stock-owned thrifts then used the money raisedfrom equity issues, mortgage sales, and brokered deposits to fund riskierportfolios than those of mutuals.

5. The FHLBB ruling in November 1982 that allowed “appraised equity capital.”An S&L that owned commercial property could credit into capital any increasein the appraised value of that property. This led to a perverse incentive to over-appraise properties in thrift’s balance sheets in order to increase its statutorycapital.

Much of the money raised by thrifts was invested in commercial and residential rental realestate ventures. Although these ventures might have been profitable by themselves, the tremendousincrease of these transactions by thrifts, coupled with the use of insured deposits to fund theseventures, led to unjustified risk-taking. Even though regulatory forbearance was reversed in the late1980s, enough S&Ls had failed through disintermediation, excessive risk-taking, compounded losses,and fraud, that by January 1987 the General Accounting Office (GAO) declared the FSLIC (which hadto rescue the depositors of the failed thrifts) insolvent by at least $3.8 billion. By 1989, when theFinancial Institutions Reform Recovery and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) was passed, the number ofFSLIC-insured S&Ls had fallen from 4,002 in 1980 (with total assets of $618.5 billion) to 2,930.

FIRREA abolished the FHLBB and FSLIC, and switched S&L regulation to the newly createdOffice of Thrift Supervision. Deposit insurance functions were shifted to the FDIC, and a new entity,the RTC, was created to liquidate the insolvent S&Ls. The RTC, which closed its doors in December1995, eventually closed or merged 747 thrifts, protected 25 million depositor accounts worth $220.6billion, and sold off more than $465 billion in assets, including 120,000 real estate properties. Thefinal cost of the bailout was estimated at $145 billion, with the RTC’s share totaling about $90 billion.6By 1995, only 1,478 S&Ls remained, with total assets of $777.4 billion.

The Future of Savings and Loans

Even while the government was, at great expense, trying to save the thrifts in the early 1990s,both of the thrifts’ economic functions of taking deposits and issuing mortgages were being takenover by other institutional mechanisms. The creation of MBS, issued initially to help the thrifts, led tothe creation of a national mortgage market that then allowed mutual funds and pension funds tobecome major funding alternatives to the thrifts. These markets also allowed the entry of investmentbanks and mortgage brokers to compete with the thrifts for the origination and servicing of loans andmortgages. On the deposit side, mutual funds and other investment vehicles competed directly withthrifts and commercial banks for deposits, further eroding the thrifts’ ability to generate new loans.

Mortgage securitization has had a tremendous impact on the structure of the S&L industry.The largest originator of mortgages in 1993 was not a thrift or a financial intermediary, butCountrywide Credit Industries, Inc., a mortgage broker. Savings institutions still originated and held

have a strong incentive to maximize the value of the residual claim at the expense of debtholders or a guarantor(e.g. the FSLIC.) In contrast, in a mutual association, the depositors are not a distinct class. There is no transferof shares, and only the face value of the deposit can be redeemed when an account is closed. Depositors haveweak incentives to increase the riskiness of the assets or to take on additional debt.6 E.J. Kane, in his book The S&L Insurance Mess (Washington, The Urban Institute Press, 1990), estimated that ifin 1983 all insolvent thrifts had been closed down, the cost to the FSLIC would have been only about $25 billion.

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets 297-090

7

mortgages for homes in their communities, but by 1993 they held only 15% of the mortgagesoutstanding, down from 60% in 1970.

There were other issues facing the thrift industry in the mid 1990s. The S&L crisis weakened theindustry. The healthy and well-managed thrifts that remained have been left to service $8 billion inbonds issued in 1987 as part of the initial recapitalization of the FSLIC. This alone will cost $780million a year for the next 24 years. Also, the deposit insurance fund created to replace the FSLIC, theSavings Association Insurance Fund (SAIF) had to be recapitalized. This cost was estimated ataround $14 billion in 1996 dollars, equivalent to a quarter of the equity base of the country’sremaining 1,500 S&Ls. The recapitalization of the SAIF was expected to take until the year 2003.

This additional burden on the S&Ls could be big enough to shift deposits from S&Ls to banks.With lower insurance premiums, banks were able to offer higher deposit rates. Even after the SAIF isrecapitalized, the servicing of the long-term bonds issued in 1987 will continue to be a burden on theremaining S&Ls.

Even if a solution is found to the costs of insurance and of servicing the bonds, the future forthrifts is unclear. One problem is competitiveness. As an industry, S&Ls made a return on assets in1995 of 56 basis points, less than half the 115 basis points of commercial banks. That reflected in partthe lower risks (and lower returns) associated with residential mortgages. However the lowprofitability also reflected lingering interest rate exposures and a failure to cut costs in a much morecompetitive mortgage market.

Additionally, there has been a structural change in the demand for mortgages from S&Ls. In thetwo decades after WW II, the assets of the thrifts grew at a rate of 15% per year, three times as fast asthose of the banks. But many in the post-war generations used banks or other lenders — insurerssuch as Prudential, or mortgage brokers such as Countrywide Credit to finance their home purchases.

In response to these threats, deregulation of the thrift industry has allowed thrifts to offer adiversified product base, including auto loans, checking accounts, and mutual funds. Ironically, thisderegulation has given thrifts, in some products, more freedom than banks. For example, S&Ls donot face the same geographic limitations as banks when it comes to selling insurance. National banksmay sell credit-related, fixed annuities without geographic restrictions. However, liability, casualty,automobile, life, health and accident insurance must also be sold in towns of 5,000 or less where thebank has a branch. Thrifts face no such restrictions. Thrifts also have the most liberal branchingrights of all federal depository institutions, and virtually unlimited holding company activities. Thismeans that any business can own a thrift through a holding company. This is not the case with banks;non-banks cannot own banks.

The answer for many to this situation is to merge the bank and thrift charters and their respectiveinsurance funds. But before that happens, there has to be a broad rewrite of banking legislation. Bothbanks and thrifts now appear to favor such reforms. After fighting for decades, the two industries areboth lobbying for legislation that could merge the bank and thrift charters. Their efforts have becomemired, however, in the ongoing discussion on the repeal of the 1934 Glass-Steagall Act separatingcommercial and investment banking.

Mortgage-Backed Securities

Aside from credit risk, the main characteristic that separates mortgages from other types offixed-income securities is the degree of uncertainty associated with the cash flows of principalrepayment and interest. Even Treasury or corporate callable bonds have provisions that prohibitcalling or refunding the bond prior to a certain date. Also, the bondholder can expect that the issuer

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

297-090 Savings and Loans and the Mortgage Markets

8

will not exercise the call option when the coupon rate is less than the current market interest rate.This is not the case with fixed-rate mortgages.

The uncertainty about the cash flows in a mortgage comes from the call option that theborrower holds to prepay (call) part or all of the mortgage at any time. Any payment that is made inexcess of the regularly scheduled principal prepayment is considered a prepayment. While theprevailing interest rates are an important determinant affecting the homeowner’s decision to prepay,other factors come into play (such as sale of the home, death of the homeowner, personal taxconsiderations, or misinformation), resulting in unexpected prepayments even when the prevailingmortgage rate is greater than the loan rate.

An investor in a pass-through security is exposed to the total prepayment risk associated withthe mortgage pool. There are two types of prepayment risk: contraction risk and extension risk.Contraction risk is the risk of prepayments when interest rates have declined, forcing the investor toreinvest the cash flow at lower (market) rates of return. Extension risk is the slowdown inprepayments when interest rates rise, resulting in reduced cash flow that can be reinvested at thehigher interest rates.

In 1983, Freddie Mac introduced a security called a collateralized mortgage obligation (or CMO).CMOS can be backed by pools of agency pass-throughs or by whole loans. In a CMO, the distributionof principal repayment (both scheduled and prepayments) is done on a prioritized basis to differenttranches, so as to redistribute prepayment risk among the different tranches. In that way, eachtranche’s prepayment schedule can be predicted much more accurately, reducing prepayment risk.

In a plain vanilla CMO, only one tranche would receive principal repayment until it wascompletely paid off. Then the second tranche would start receiving principal repayments until thistranche was completely paid off. The CMO tranches are usually labeled alphabetically, with the lasttranche to pay off always known as the Z tranche. Other kinds of CMOs, such as the plannedamortization class (PAC) bonds, or the Targeted Amortization class (TAC) bonds, are designed to havemore precise estimates of prepayments, or to protect investors only against extension or contractionrisk, but not both.

In 1986, another type of derivative MBS was introduced by Fannie Mae. This security isknown as the stripped MBS. In a stripped MBS, all of the interest from the pass-through is distributedto one tranche, known as the Interest Only class, or IO “strip”, while all the principal was assigned tothe Principal Only class, or PO “strip”. Stripped MBS allowed investors to create synthetic securitieswith risk-return profiles not available in standard CMOs, and provided institutional investors withinstruments that could be used to more effectively hedge their liabilities.

For the exclusive use of L. Gao, 2022.

This document is authorized for use only by Liwen Gao in MET AD 712 – Spring 2 2022 taught by Emily Helter, Boston University from Feb 2022 to Aug 2022.

You can leave a response, or trackback from your own site.

Leave a Reply

Powered by WordPress | Designed by: Premium WordPress Themes | Thanks to Themes Gallery, Bromoney and Wordpress Themes